Heterogeneity in the Response to Gasoline Prices: Evidence from Pennsylvania and Implications for the Rebound Effect ǂ

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Heterogeneity in the Response to Gasoline Prices: Evidence from Pennsylvania and Implications for the Rebound Effect ǂ"

Transcription

1 Heterogeneity in the Response to Gasoline Prices: Evidence from Pennsylvania and Implications for the Rebound Effect ǂ Kenneth Gillingham *, Alan Jenn **, Inês Lima Azevedo ** * School of Forestry & Environmental Studies, Department of Economics, School of Management, Yale University and National Bureau of Economic Research ** Department of Engineering and Public Policy, Carnegie-Mellon University Forthcoming in Energy Economics September 5, 2015 Abstract The consumer response to changing gasoline prices has long interested economists and policymakers, for it has important implications for the effects of gasoline taxation and vehicle energy efficiency policies. This study examines both the elasticity of driving with respect to changing gasoline prices and heterogeneity in this elasticity by geography, the fuel economy of the vehicle, and the age of the vehicle. We use detailed annual vehiclelevel emissions inspection test data from Pennsylvania that include odometer readings, inspection zip codes, and extensive vehicle characteristics. We estimate a short-run gasoline price elasticity of driving demand of -0.10, and find substantial heterogeneity in this responsiveness. The elasticity is largely driven by low fuel economy vehicles, as well as vehicles between 3 and 7 years old. Our findings help reconcile some of the recent literature and provide guidance on the magnitude of the direct rebound effect from light duty vehicle energy efficiency policies. JEL classification codes: H23, Q38, Q41. Keywords: energy efficiency, rebound effect, gasoline price elasticity, big data analytics. ǂ We thank audiences at the 6 th Atlantic Workshop on Energy & Environmental Economics, the Industry Studies Association 2014, and the 2013 Behavior, Energy, and Climate Change Conference, as well as Jeremy Michalek, Pedro Ferreira, Paul Fischbeck, and Scott Matthews for comments. This work was supported by the center for Climate and Energy Decision Making (SES ), through a cooperative agreement between the National Science Foundation and Carnegie Mellon University. We also acknowledge support from a Bertucci Fellowship through Carnegie Mellon University. Corresponding author: Kenneth Gillingham, Yale University and NBER, 195 Prospect Street, New Haven, CT 06510, , kenneth.gillingham@yale.edu. 1

2 1 Introduction The United States consumes over 130 billion gallons of gasoline annually, with the vast majority used in the transportation sector. The use of fossil fuel in transportation leads to nearly 2 billion metric tons of CO2 being emitted into the atmosphere every year in the US approximately one-third of US greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions (EPA, 2014). In an effort to reduce these emissions and imported oil, policymakers have implemented a variety of measures, from Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standards and the Zero Emissions Vehicle (ZEV) mandate, to Renewable Fuel Standards (RFS) and Low Carbon Fuel Standards (LCFS). In addition, the gasoline tax has been falling in real terms across the United States (Jenn et al., 2015). The effects of changes in policies such as gasoline taxes and fuel economy standards depend critically on the consumer responsiveness to changes in relative prices engendered by the policies. This paper examines how consumers change the amount they drive in response to changing gasoline prices and the heterogeneity in this response. Such heterogeneity could come about due to different preferences, different urban spatial structures, and differences in the cost or appeal of driving different types of vehicles. In this study we address the following questions: are some consumers more responsive than others? Is the response greater for different types of vehicles than others, perhaps by fuel economy or age of vehicle? To answer these questions, we use a massive dataset of over 75 million inspection records, which include odometer readings, covering 2000 to We find a point estimate for the one-year gasoline price elasticity of driving of However, quantile regressions reveal that a high percentage of the vehicles are almost entirely inelastic in response to gasoline price changes. Further, we find that the lowest fuel economy vehicles in the fleet drive the responsiveness, with higher fuel economy vehicles highly inelastic with respect to gasoline price changes. Similarly, we find considerable heterogeneity in the response by the age of the vehicle, with drivers of vehicles in the age bracket of 3 to 7 years being the most responsive. 2

3 These results not only shed light on the differing effects of changes in gasoline prices, but also have clear implications for policy. If consumers respond in the same way to changes in gasoline prices and gasoline taxes, as might be expected, then our estimates can be interpreted as the effect on driving from a marginal increase in the gasoline tax. 1 Our results thus provide guidance for the additional driving that might be expected due to declining real gasoline taxes. In addition, they also have implications for the gasoline and greenhouse gas savings possible from fuel economy standards. With an improvement in fuel economy, the cost per mile of driving decreases and consumers would be expected to drive more. This effect has come to be known in the energy economics literature as the direct rebound effect: an increase in energy use that reduces or even eliminates the energy and greenhouse gas savings that would have been expected from the efficiency improvement (Azevedo, 2014; Gillingham et al., 2016; Sorrell, 2007; Thomas and Azevedo, 2014). It is considered a key parameter in the analysis of the costs and benefits of fuel economy standards; indeed findings of positive net benefits often turn on this parameter (Gillingham et al., 2016). It is common convention to use the price elasticity of demand for driving as a proxy for direct rebound effect, a convention that is valid under several assumptions, including that there are few substitute goods and that consumers respond the same way to changes in the cost per mile of driving regardless of the source of the variation (e.g., gasoline price changes or fuel efficiency changes) (Chan and Gillingham, 2015; Thomas and Azevedo, 2013). 2 Thus, our baseline result may be interpreted as a proxy for the rebound effect, while the finding of heterogeneity in responsiveness by vehicle type may extend to heterogeneity in the rebound effect. However, as the true direct rebound effect is by definition calculated based on an unobserved counterfactual where fuel economy (not fuel prices) change, we are cautious in this interpretation. Moreover, our findings of heterogeneity in the response to gasoline prices by 1 It is possible that consumers respond differently to changes in taxes than to changes in prices, perhaps due to differences in salience (Li et al., 2014). 2 An important reason for using gasoline price variation is that there is usually only cross-sectional variation in fuel economy, which is less plausibly exogenous and perhaps more difficult to instrument for than time series variation in gasoline prices. 3

4 vehicle fuel economy and age raise further questions about the validity of the assumption that consumers respond the same way to changes in the cost per mile of driving regardless of the source of the variation. The remainder of our paper is structured as follows. The next section discusses the relevant literature, while Section 3 describes our unique and rich registration dataset. Section 4 covers our empirical strategy for estimating driving demand. Section 5 presents our results and Section 6 concludes. 2 Relevant Literature This paper relates to an extensive empirical literature on gasoline price elasticities of demand, but is one of only a few papers to estimate a gasoline price elasticity of demand for driving, rather than demand for gasoline. Of course, the two elasticities are closely related, for the price elasticity of gasoline demand can be decomposed into responses on both the intensive margin (i.e., driving) and extensive margins (i.e., new vehicle purchase and scrappage), with the gasoline price elasticity of driving capturing the response on the intensive margin (Gillingham, 2011). One of the earliest reviews of studies estimating the price elasticity of the demand for gasoline finds a mean (across studies) short-run estimate of based on studies from 1979 to 1991 (Dahl and Sterner, 1991). A somewhat more recent review of studies from 1967 to 2000 finds estimates in the range of to (Greening et al., 2000). 3 These earlier reviewed estimates did not have the benefit of the rich datasets available today and in many cases did not carefully consider possible endogeneity concerns. More recently, there has been work indicating that the price elasticity of gasoline demand has been decreasing over time in the United States. Using different approaches and datasets, both Small and Van Dender (2007b) (using pooled cross section data for the US states from 1966 to 2001) and Hughes et al. (2008) (who examined gasoline demand from 1975 to 1980 and 2001 to 3 Other notable reviews include Goodwin et al. (2004) and Graham and Glaister (2004), both which review estimates ranging widely from near-zero to close to -1. 4

5 2006) show that during the period of relatively low and stable gasoline prices in the late 1990s and early-to-mid 2000s, consumers appear to have become even more inelastic, with estimated short-run gasoline demand elasticities in the to range. These findings suggest that consumer responsiveness may vary depending on conditions, much as Gately and Huntington (2002) show that there is an asymmetric consumer response to increases and decreases in oil prices. The possibility of varying consumer responsiveness is further underscored by a set of more recent results that include data from the late 2000s, when gasoline prices were rapidly changing. Hymel and Small (2014) update the previous Small and Van Dender (2007b) analysis to 2009, and find evidence of a slightly greater responsiveness during this time period. This result would help reconcile the previous findings with recent results using odometer reading data in the late 2000s showing a much more elastic response in the gasoline price elasticity of driving in California; Gillingham et al. (2013) estimates a two-year gasoline price elasticity of driving for new vehicles of and Knittel and Sandler (2013) estimates a two-year gasoline price elasticity of driving for all but the newest vehicles of This difference already suggests that consumers of vehicles of different ages may respond differently, possibly due to different needs, preferences, or locations. Our finding of a greater responsiveness for drivers of lower fuel economy vehicles corresponds with similar findings from California by Knittel and Sandler (2013) and Germany by Frondel et al. (2012). What is new about our result is that it is based on actual annual odometer reading data from all vehicles in a large area, rather than just older vehicles in California or trip diary data from Germany. Similarly, Gillingham (2011), Frondel et al. (2012) and Gillingham (2014) also use quantile regression approaches to examine the driving responsiveness to gasoline prices, but this is the first paper to both examine all vehicles using revealed odometer readings and include fixed effects in the quantile regressions to address potentially correlated unobservables. A few key points emerge from the literature, which are relevant to interpreting our results. Since these estimated elasticities are often being used in policymaking as a proxy for the rebound 5

6 effect from fuel economy standards, they suggest that the rebound effect may be changing over time and across geography. Furthermore, the few studies that attempt to estimate the rebound effect more directly through an elasticity of vehicle-miles-traveled (VMT) with respect to fuel economy, such as Small and Van Dender (2007b), generally are in the same order of magnitude, and with similar variation, as the studies discussed above that focus on the fuel price elasticity (Azevedo, 2014). While we are careful about interpreting our estimates directly as a rebound effect, we believe that they contribute to the literature suggesting that the price elasticity of driving and the rebound effect may be heterogeneous and relatively close to zero in the short run. 3 Data 3.1 The Pennsylvania Inspection Program This paper uses a dataset of over 7 million light duty vehicles, covering the years 2000 to 2010, resulting in over 75 million vehicle inspection records from mandatory annual inspections in Pennsylvania. These annual inspections involve both a visual safety check and an on-board diagnostic (OBD) test that electronically records and submits emissions, odometer readings, zip code of the inspection station, other vehicle information, and the date of inspection to the Pennsylvania Department of Transportation. All light duty vehicles in Pennsylvania with a model year after 1975, including hybrid electric vehicles, are required to undergo the mandatory safety and emissions inspection. In addition, a new inspection is required any time there is an update to a vehicle registration, such as a change of address or ownership. In the case of a failed inspection, drivers must repair the vehicle and follow up with a free inspection within 30 days. 4 The mandatory inspection program was rolled out over a several year period and with start dates differing across Pennsylvania regions. The roll out of the inspection program started with the most populated regions (e.g., the Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metropolitan areas) in These regions have the greatest air quality challenges and thus were prioritized for the program. In the following years, the program was rolled out to other regions that also faced air quality challenges. 4 Drivers may also opt to receive a 1-year waiver if repair costs exceed $150. 6

7 Figure 1 illustrates the roll-out of the inspection program with a map of Pennsylvania that shows when mandatory inspections began in each zip code. This figure illustrates that all of the most populated areas in Pennsylvania are required to undergo a mandatory inspection by around The areas of the state that do not require mandatory inspections tend to be rural and mountainous, and host a smaller share of the Pennsylvania light duty vehicle fleet. 5 OBD Inspections Introduced Pittsburgh Philadelphia Figure 1: Zip codes by date for which the inspections requirements were introduced in Pennsylvania, from 2000 through Annual inspections are not required in the white areas of the state. Source: The inspection program only covers light duty passenger vehicles, which make up roughly 70 percent of the vehicle fleet in Pennsylvania (PennDOT, 2010). Figure 2 shows the percentage of the total light duty vehicle fleet in Pennsylvania covered by the inspection program in each year. By the end of our sample, in 2010, roughly two-thirds of all light duty vehicles undertook an inspection and are included in our dataset. Any vehicles not recorded were either in violation of the law, in zip codes that were not subject to the mandatory inspections or were sold before Since the program roll out took some time to get started in late 2000, the first inspections for most vehicles in Philadelphia and Pittsburgh were in The same is true for vehicles in regions where the program was rolled out in 2004; these vehicles generally had their first inspections in A full list of exempted regions can be found at 7

8 8 Number of Records (millions) Record Type Inspections Remaining Registrations Year Figure 2: Total registered vehicles (blue + green) and number of inspection records in our dataset (green). Sources: PennDOT inspection data and In the regions covered by the inspection program, there are important patterns in the data that bear relevance to interpreting our results. First, vehicles are not located uniformly. Certain regions of Pennsylvania make up a much larger portion of our dataset than others, as is illustrated in Figure 3, which plots the number of inspections by the zip code of the inspection. Notably, the areas with the greatest number of inspections appear to be in the larger Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metropolitan areas (largely in the suburbs of these cities). Thus, these areas will be heavily weighted in our regression results. 8

9 Pittsburgh Philadelphia Figure 3: Number of vehicles in our dataset by zip code in Source: PennDOT inspection data. Second, the areas with the most vehicle inspections per household are distributed across Pennsylvania in a somewhat more uniform pattern (Figure 4). In general it appears that the suburban areas in the Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metropolitan areas have slightly more vehicles per household than other areas, but there is no strong and obvious pattern. One caveat to this is that we only observe the zip code where vehicles are inspected, which may differ slightly from where the vehicles are garaged. 9

10 Pittsburgh Philadelphia Figure 4. Vehicles per household by zip code in Pennsylvania in Source: PennDOT inspection data and households from the 2010 US Census. 3.2 Construction of the Panel Dataset We begin with over 75 million vehicle inspection records over the period 2000 to 2010, each with an odometer reading. We are interested in the miles driven during the period between two inspections, and follow the strategy from several other recent papers in the literature that have odometer reading data (Gillingham, 2014; Knittel and Sandler, 2013) by using the vehicledriving period as our unit of observation. Consider a case where one inspection was on July 1, 2001, with an odometer reading of 30,000, and the next inspection was on June 1, 2002, with an odometer reading of 41,000. Then a vehicle-driving period level observation for this driving period would have a VMT of 11,000, a time between inspections of 11 months, and a second test date of June 1, For interpretability, we normalize VMT to be in terms of VMT per year based on the number of days in the driving period. So in our simplified example, the VMT per 10

11 year would be coded to 12,000. Converting our data to the vehicle-driving period level leaves us with 34,596,513 observations. 6 Each vehicle in the dataset is indexed by a Vehicle Identification Number (VIN), which we decode using a VIN decoder from DataOne, Inc. to reveal the following vehicle information: make, model, model year, body style, body type, engine type, engine size, fuel type, drive type, highway fuel economy in miles per gallon (MPG), weight, and manufacturer s suggested retail price (MSRP). We create a variable for vehicle age by subtracting the model year from the year of the inspection. 7 We are able to decode the VINs for 97 percent of the observations in the dataset. The remainder are either invalid VINs or for vehicles prior to 1980 and we drop these observations. Since we are interested in the response in VMT to changing gasoline prices, we bring in monthly Pennsylvania gasoline price data from EIA (2014). Similarly, we bring in macroeconomic conditions: the monthly average U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA, 2014) and the average unemployment rate in Pennsylvania based on data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS, 2014). Finally, we also bring in data on major refinery supply disruptions in the Gulf Coast (primarily due to hurricanes) from the Energy Information Administration (EIA, 2011). All four of these variables are at the monthly level in raw data form and are converted to the vehicle-driving period level. This is accomplished by taking the average value for each over the months of the driving period covered by each observation. This means that for vehicle i that performed an inspection in time t and the subsequent inspection in time t + m, we compute the average gasoline price, GDP, unemployment, and supply disruptions between t and t +m for that observation. So, for example, we compute the price of gasoline for the driving period of a vehicle inspected first on July 1st, 6 The 34.6 million driving periods are less than half of the 75 million inspection records because of vehicles that only had one inspection, such as new vehicles or vehicles that left the state shortly after the program began. 7 We recognize that some vehicles may be sold before the model year or after the model year, so this is a proxy for the actual vehicle age. However, this proxy is what is typically used for used car pricing (e.g., see the Kelley Blue Book), so it is as good as possible without actual data on when the new vehicle was first purchased. 11

12 2001 and then on June 1st, 2002 as the average of the monthly gasoline prices in the 11 months between inspections. Finally, to address potential outliers, we truncate our data and drop observations where vehicles were not used (e.g. a VMT of 0), as well as vehicles with VMT per driving period greater than 100,000 miles or odometer readings greater than 7,000,000 miles, which are likely inspection reporting errors. The final panel dataset contains 30,621,721 observations and 7,173,110 distinct vehicles. We convert all dollar-valued variables to real 2010 dollars using the BLS Consumer Price Index. 3.3 Data Description Table 1 presents summary statistics for key variables in the final full dataset. The average annual VMT is 10,183 miles, with a standard deviation that is nearly as large, at 7,303 miles. The average gasoline price is $2.46/gallon, with a standard deviation of $0.55/gallon. Table 1: Summary statistics for selected variables in the full dataset. Mean Std. dev. Min. Max. Annual VMT (mi) 10, ,000 Average Gas Price (2010$/gal) MPG Highway (mi/gal) Age (years) Avg Adjusted Unemployment (%) Avg GDP (billions of 2010$) 14, ,634 15,056 Avg Refinery Disruptions (millions of barrels) Notes: All variables have 30,621,721 non-missing observations. The age of the vehicle is in the number of years between the model year and the year of the second test in a driving period. Figure 5 illustrates the variation in annual VMT in Pennsylvania over the full sample. The VMT distribution appears to have a zero-truncated normal distribution, with a long 12

13 tail of drivers who drive a substantial amount (e.g., 60,000 miles per year is over 160 miles per day). Frequency 0 200, , , , Annual VMT (miles) Figure 5. Histogram of the annual vehicle miles driven in Pennsylvania. Source: PennDOT inspection data. The variation in driving may stem from a variety of sources, including geographic heterogeneity. Figure 6 shows how VMT differs considerably across Pennsylvania (for observations from all years), with vehicles being driven the most located in rural and suburban areas. This likely reflects the greater need to drive in these areas. 13

14 Philadelphia Pittsburgh Figure 6. Average annual VMT by zip code, Source: PennDOT inspection data. Figure 7 shows the changes in the average gasoline price and macroeconomic conditions over the time period of analysis. Gasoline prices display considerable time-series variation, with a dramatic and sustained increase in prices from 2004 to 2008, followed by a steep decline in 2008 and a leveling off afterwards. This variation will be leveraged for identifying our coefficients. Average PA Gas Prices ($) Time (monthly) Gross Domestic Product GDP Unemployment Time (monthly) Unemployment Index Figure 7. Gasoline prices (in $2010) have considerable time series variation during our time period (Left). Macroeconomic conditions ($2010 trillion U.S. GDP and Pennsylvania unemployment) also changed substantially over this time (Right). Sources: US EIA, US BEA, US BLS. 14

15 In Figure 8, we provide descriptive evidence on trends in the average annual gasoline price and average annual VMT over each driving period in our full sample. The solid lines show that the mean VMT has decreased slightly over this period, while the mean gasoline price has increased over this period. The wide bands of the dotted around the solid lines show plus or minus one standard deviation in the variables (based on the year of the second inspection of the driving period). Figure 8. The average annual gasoline price and VMT are shown in the solid lines, with +/- one standard deviation shown in the dotted lines for each. The year on the x-axis denotes the year of the second test of a driving period. Sources: US EIA and PennDOT inspection data. Figure 8 descriptively suggests only a relatively minor response in driving to gasoline prices. Of course, as shown in Figure 7, macroeconomic conditions also changed, so our empirical specification will control for these changes. 15

16 As mentioned above, vehicles in the Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metropolitan areas not only have more vehicles, but also began receiving inspections much earlier than the rest of Pennsylvania, most of which began inspections after To illustrate the differences between these two subsamples, Table 2 provides summary statistics for the subsample of all vehicles that begin inspections in 2000 (Philadelphia and Pittsburgh) and all vehicles that began inspections in 2004 (many other parts of the state). Note that both the time frames and the regions differ, so one must be cautious in interpreting these as only regional differences or differences due to time. Table 2: Summary statistics by geographic region based on introduction of OBD inspections. Mean Std dev. Min. Max. OBD Inspections begun in 2000 Annual VMT (mi) 9, ,000 Average Gas Price (2010$/gal) Combined MPG (mi/gal) Age (years) Avg Adjusted Unemployment (%) Avg GDP (trillions of 2010$) 14, ,634 15,056 Avg Refinery Disruptions (millions of barrels) OBD Inspections begun in 2004 Annual VMT (mi) 9,861 6, ,000 Average Gas Price (2010$/gal) Combined MPG (mi/gal) Age (years) Avg Adjusted Unemployment (%) Avg GDP (trillions of 2010$) 14, ,256 15,056 Avg Refinery Disruptions (millions of barrels) Notes: All variables in the 2000 inspections panel have 18,642,460 non-missing values, while all variables in the 2004 inspections panel have 3,097,592 non-missing values. Note that these do not add up to 30 million because the remaining vehicles entered the dataset in other years. The age of the vehicle is in the number of years between the vehicle model year and the year of the second test in a driving period. 16

17 4 Empirical Approach 4.1 Model specification We model the demand for driving vehicle i with a test in year t and j months between tests as a function of the Pennsylvania gasoline price ( ), national GDP ( ), unemployment rate in Pennsylvania ( ) the age of the vehicle ( ), vehicle characteristics ( ), other broader timevarying factors ( ), month-of-the-year seasonal factors ( ) and any factors that relate to the length of the driving periods ( ):,,,,,,,. Controls for factors that relate to the length of the driving period are included because there may be potentially correlated unobserved heterogeneity in drivers based on when they receive their inspection (e.g., those who get a late inspection may drive differently than those who get an on-time inspection, and their driving period will cover a different time frame of gasoline prices). We further specify demand as follows: exp, where. is a quadratic function in age, which flexibly captures the relationship between vehicle age and driving. is a mean-zero stochastic error term. This specification implies the following log-log form: log log log, (1) where, and γ is our parameter of interest, which can be interpreted as the elasticity of VMT with respect to the price of gasoline. Given that inspections are generally once a year, any estimate is best understood as a one-year elasticity of driving (i.e., a short-run elasticity). are vehicle fixed effects.,, and are indicator variables for the year that the driving period 17

18 finishes, the month-of-the-year that the driving period finishes, and driving period length categories (early tests that are less than 11 months, normal tests between 11 months and 13 months, late tests between 14 and 21 months, and very late tests beyond this). 8 We estimate this equation using a standard fixed effects regression as well as using a quantile regression (Koenker and Bassett, 1978) to understand the heterogeneity in responsiveness across consumers. Furthermore, to better understand the sources of heterogeneity, we also estimate (1) using partitions of our dataset based on fuel economy and vehicle age. The model in (1) follows most of the existing literature in that it implies that consumers respond symmetrically to increases and decreases in gasoline prices. In this sense, our results just like most others should be viewed as estimating an average response. 4.2 Identification and potential estimation concerns With the inclusion of such a rich set of fixed effects, the model specifications we estimate address a variety of potential empirical concerns. For example, vehicle fixed effects capture unobserved heterogeneity in time-invariant vehicle characteristics, location, and driver attributes. 9 Gillingham (2013) shows that estimates of the demand for driving can be biased upwards due to unobserved preferences for driving that lead consumers to purchase a more efficient vehicle. By including vehicle fixed effects, we address this unobserved heterogeneity in a flexible non-parametric way. Year-of-test indicator variables address time-varying factors besides the macroeconomic conditions that we already control for. Month-of-the-year indicator variables capture the possibility that different types of consumers purchase vehicles at different times of year (Copeland et al., 2011), and thus have inspections performed during that time of year in subsequent years. Finally, indicator variables for the length of the driving period flexibly control for possible heterogeneity in consumers who have their inspection done on time or at different times. 8 Our results are robust to the exact specification of these indicator variables. 9 Note that some vehicles move the location of their inspections during our time period. These movers correspond to much less than 1% of the observations in the dataset. We observe these movers and find that excluding the movers from our analysis makes little difference. Thus we opt to include them and simply use vehicle fixed effects. 18

19 Including the rich set of fixed effects is very useful for identifying the relationship between gasoline prices and VMT by addressing a variety of potential confounders. Yet, we recognize that there remains a possible concern about the classic simultaneity of supply and demand. This issue is beautifully described on page 1 in Kennan (1989): For example, even if each buyer has a negligible influence on the market price, there may still be an important correlation between the price and the disturbance in an individual demand equation, so that treating price as econometrically exogenous gives biased coefficient estimates. Fundamentally, the concern is that unobserved local demand shocks will shift demand, increasing the gasoline price in equilibrium and leading to a supply response (e.g., immediately refining more gasoline and moving it to Pennsylvania). We would then be estimating an equilibrium response, rather than actually pinning down the demand curve. While we expect that our rich set of fixed effects should address most of these issues, we grant that some may remain. Thus, in our preferred specification, we instrument for the gasoline price with an exogenous supply shifter: major gasoline refining supply disruptions in Gulf Coast due to hurricane activity. This instrument is highly correlated with the Pennsylvania gasoline price, due to the integration of the gasoline market in much of the United States. Yet there is no reason to believe that it is correlated with local demand factors in Pennsylvania, except through the gasoline price. A similar oil price shock instrument was also used in Hughes et al. (2008). It is worth noting that our empirical strategy, while flexibly controlling for key estimation concerns, does impose some structure to the relationship between gasoline prices and VMT. There has been a series of papers on the gasoline price elasticity of demand that use semiparametric or non-parametric estimation approaches (Blundell et al., 2012; Hausman and Newey, 1995; Liu, 2014; Schmalenesee and Stoker, 1999; Wadud et al., 2010b; Yatchew and No, 2001). While of merit, these approaches often also impose some structure, albeit less than in our specification. But more importantly these approaches cannot flexibly control for potential confounders with a rich set of fixed effects (usually because the data available for estimation 19

20 does not permit rich sets of fixed effects). We deem that the value of the fixed effects approach, and especially vehicle fixed effects, for identification of our coefficients is sufficient to opt for our approach rather than a semi-parametric or non-parametric approach Results 5.1 The gasoline price elasticity of driving We begin by estimating (1) on the full dataset of over 30 million observations. Table 3 shows our primary results. Column 1 contains year (, month-of-the-year ( ), and driving period length ( ) indicator variables. Column 2 contains vehicle fixed effects ( ), but none of the other indicator variables. Column 3 contains year, month-of-the-year, and months-to-test indicator variables, as well as vehicle fixed effects. Column 4 is the same as column 3, but with the log of the average gasoline price instrumented for using the log of the average size of the oil refinery disruptions (in millions of barrels of oil). The first-stage results from this IV estimation are available in the appendix. The instrument is very strong: the t-statistic on the log refinery disruptions coefficient in the first-stage is over 1, Gillingham and Munk-Nielsen (2015) explore this issue in more detail using rich data from Denmark and find similar results with semi-parametric and vehicle fixed effects approaches. We also explore other functional forms, such as a linear form, and find largely similar results. 20

21 Table 3: Primary regression results with full dataset. (1) Time Controls (2) Vehicle FE (3) All FE (4) All FE; IV ln(gasoline price) *** *** *** *** (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.008) ln(gdp) 6.32*** 2.09*** 3.85*** 3.18*** (0.033) (0.021) (0.041) (0.056) ln(unemployment) 0.765*** 0.213*** 0.311*** 0.328*** (0.004) (0.002) (0.005) (0.004) age *** *** *** *** (2.21E-4) (4.19E-4) (8.40E-4) (7.38E-4) age *** *** *** -1.79E-3*** (1.24E-5) (1.66E-5) (1.66E-5) (1.52E-5) vehicle fixed effects X X X year dummies X X X month-of-year dummies X X X driving period dummies X X X R-squared N 30,621,721 30,621,721 30,621,721 30,621,721 Notes: Dependent variable is the log average VMT over a driving period. Column 4 instruments for the log gasoline price with the log of the average size of the refinery disruptions over the driving period. For column 4, the within R-squared is reported. Robust standard errors clustered on vehicle in parentheses. *** denotes significant at the 1% level. In all four specifications, the coefficient on the log of the average gasoline price our estimated gasoline price elasticity of driving indicates a highly inelastic response to gasoline prices. The coefficient ranges from to Our preferred specification is in column 4, which implies a one-year price elasticity of demand for driving of This result of an inelastic short-run response to gasoline prices is in line with much of the literature for the United States. For context, it implies slightly more responsiveness than Small and van Dender (2007a) 21

22 and slightly less responsiveness than estimates by Gillingham (2014) and Knittel and Sandler (2013) for California. It also implies much less responsiveness than estimates using German travel diary data by Frondel et al. (2012), which show elasticities in the range of -0.4 to These differences across studies over different times and locations may belie the heterogeneity in responsiveness by time frame and location. Our other coefficients in Table 3 are included as controls. The macroeconomic variables are positive and statistically significant in all specifications. There is a sensible interpretation for the coefficient on GDP: more economic growth implies more driving. The positive coefficient on unemployment may indicate that when unemployment is high workers are more likely to take jobs further away from home, leading to more driving. This especially makes sense after controlling for GDP, since GDP most likely captures changes in leisure driving due to increased income that could possibly correlated with gasoline prices. 11 The vehicle age coefficients suggest that vehicles are driven less as they age, consistent with previous findings in other settings (Gillingham, 2011). The quadratic term is very close to zero, so the relationship appears to be close to linear. The relationship is slightly concave, consistent with driving a similar amount for several years as a vehicle ages and then dropping more steeply in driving once the vehicle is older, as one might expect. Older vehicles are often kept as a second or third vehicle in a household and they may be driven by retired drivers. We cannot test these possible explanations in our data. However, we do explore the responsiveness by the age the vehicle in section 5.4. One interesting feature of our dataset is that in the first few years of our sample we only observe vehicles in the Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metropolitan areas, while mid-way through the sample, we begin to observe vehicles from many other areas in Pennsylvania (Figure 2). While our year fixed effects should largely address any concern from the sample changing over time, we also perform the estimations separately on the Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metropolitan 11 Removing unemployment altogether from the regression does not change our coefficient on the gasoline price in any substantive way. 22

23 areas and on the remaining areas in Pennsylvania to provide insight into how the response may differ. Table 4 shows the results of these estimations of Equation (1) on the two subsamples. Columns 1 and 2 estimate the model for the metropolitan areas in Pennsylvania (from 2000 to 2010), while columns 3 and 4 estimate the model on the remaining areas of Pennsylvania that require an inspection starting in 2004 (from 2004 to 2010). All columns have the full set of fixed effects and indicator variables, while columns 2 and 4 instrument for the gasoline price. Table 4: Estimation on the two subsamples based on year of mandatory OBD inspections. (1) OBD 2000 (2) OBD 2000; IV (3) OBD 2004 (4) OBD 2004; IV ln(gasoline price) *** *** *** *** (0.063) (0.015) (0.011) (0.0237) ln(gdp) 2.31*** 3.33*** 4.38*** 4.31*** (0.053) (0.082) (0.164) (0.240) ln(unemployment) 0.301*** 0.398*** 0.412*** 0.429*** (0.006) (0.006) (0.016) (0.014) age *** *** *** *** (0.001) (9.25E-4) (0.003) (0.002) age E-3*** -1.76E-3*** -2.46E-3*** -2.42E-3*** (2.07E-5) (1.84E-5) (4.49E-5) (3.98E-5) vehicle fixed effects X X X X year dummies X X X X month-of-year dummies X X X X driving period dummies X X X X R-squared N 18,642,460 18,642,460 3,097,592 3,097,592 Notes: Dependent variable is the log average VMT over a driving period. Columns 1 and 2 are estimated on the subsample that first required inspections in 2000 (i.e., Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metro areas). Columns 3 and 4 are estimated on the subsample that first required inspections in Columns 2 and 4 instrument for the log 23

24 gasoline price with the log of the average size of the refinery disruptions over the driving period. The within R- squared is presented for columns 2 and 4. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at the vehicle level. *** denotes significant at the 1% level. We find that our results are relatively robust to partitioning the data into these two samples. At -0.08, the estimated elasticity in the Philadelphia and Pittsburgh municipality regions is just slightly less than the elasticity in column 4 of Table 4. In the remaining regions (with data only available from 2004 onwards and excluding Pittsburgh and Philadelphia), the estimate is These results appear to contrast with the results in Wadud et al. (2010a), which use U.S. survey data to find that drivers in urban areas in the United States are more responsive than those rural areas. One explanation for this greater responsiveness may be that the sample only includes a later time period that has higher and more volatile gasoline prices. Lin and Prince (2013) provide evidence indicating that the price elasticity of gasoline demand is nearly twice as high during the 2007 to 2012 period (e.g., a period of high volatility) than the 2000 to 2006 period using aggregate monthly time series data for the United States. However, when we estimate the elasticity using the OBD 2000 vehicles (Philadelphia and Pittsburgh), but only for tests after 2005, we find only a slight change in the elasticity, with an estimated coefficient of in the IV specification. Another explanation is that the more rural areas have a different population and vehicle stock than the Philadelphia and Pittsburgh metropolitan areas. As shown in Table 2, the average age of vehicles is lower in the remaining regions than in metropolitan areas, perhaps suggesting that heterogeneity in the response by vehicle attributes may be an important part of the explanation. 5.2 Heterogeneity in responsiveness by quantile Quantile regressions are well-suited for examining the heterogeneity in the response across consumers. There are several approaches used in the literature to estimate quantile regression models with panel data. We adopt the approach of Canay (2011). The approach is quite simple. 24

25 First we perform our instrumental variable within-estimation with vehicle fixed effects ( ). We then estimate these individual fixed effects as the sample mean of the residual taken over each vehicle. Finally, we perform a standard quantile regression of log log on all of the covariates in (1), but with no vehicle fixed effects. Canay (2011) shows that this approach provides a consistent quantile fixed effects estimator as and. By comparing the 0.25 quantile estimated elasticity to 0.5 (median) and 0.75 quantile elasticities in Table 5, we can see the breadth of responsiveness to gasoline price changes across the population. For computational reasons, we estimate the model on a randomly drawn subsample of 10% of the vehicles in the full dataset. 25

26 Table 5: Quantile regression results. (1) 0.25 Quantile; IV (2) 0.5 Quantile; IV (3) 0.75 Quantile; IV ln(gasoline price) *** *** (0.021) (0.001) (0.002) ln(gdp) 6.232*** 7.117*** 4.483*** (0.376) (0.342) (0.375) ln(unemployment) 0.835*** 0.944*** 0.692*** (0.053) (0.049) (0.053) Age *** *** (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) age *** *** *** (7.48E-5) (4.73E-5) (6.80E-5) vehicle fixed effects X X X year dummies X X X month-to-test dummies X X X driving period dummies X X X N 3,062,172 3,062,172 3,062,172 Notes: Dependent variable is the log average VMT over the driving period scaled to one year. The results are based on a randomly drawn subsample of 10% of the full dataset. All columns instrument for the log gasoline price with the log of the average size of the refinery disruptions over the driving period. Standard errors in parentheses. *** denotes significant at the 1% level. Vehicle fixed effects accounted for using the Canay (2011) quantile fixed effects estimator. The results in Table 5 show clear heterogeneity in the response to gasoline prices. At the 0.25 quantile of the responsiveness, the elasticity is near-zero and statistically insignificant. The estimated elasticity from the median regression is statistically significant and closer to zero than our estimated elasticity in our mean regression in Table 3, at On the other end, the 0.75 quantile elasticity is statistically significant and larger than our mean elasticity, at

27 The heterogeneity we find in this setting is consistent with findings in Gillingham (2014), but the magnitude of the response is substantively less here. Such a difference may be due to differences in the sample: our sample contains most vehicles in Pennsylvania, rather than new vehicles in California. We now seek to explain some of this heterogeneity in responsiveness in two key vehicle attributes with policy relevance: fuel economy and age. 5.3 Heterogeneity in responsiveness by fuel economy One might expect that consumers who drive less efficient vehicles would be more responsive to gasoline price changes since they face a greater burden at the pump. This would be particularly interesting for two reasons. First, if less efficient vehicles are more responsive, as fuel economy standards in the United States ramp up consumers may become even less responsive to changes in gasoline prices into the future. Second, if less efficient vehicles are more responsive, the emissions may be reduced by more than would be expected based on the mean elasticity, for less efficient vehicles have a higher emissions rate (Knittel and Sandler, 2013). We examine heterogeneity based on vehicle fuel economy by estimating the model given in (1) on three partitions of the dataset. Our results are robust to the exact partitions we choose, so for ease of interpretability, Table 6 presents the results for three groups: vehicles with fuel economy less than 20 MPG (column 2), vehicles with fuel economy between 20 and 30 MPG (column 3), and vehicles with fuel economy greater than 30 MPG (column 4). Column 1 provides the estimation results using the full dataset for reference. Table 6: Regression results on subsamples of the dataset based on fuel economy groups. (1) (2) (3) (4) Full Dataset; IV FE<20 MPG; IV FE20-30 MPG; IV FE>30 MPG; IV ln(gasoline price) *** *** (0.008) (0.013) (0.012) (0.067) ln(gdp) 3.18*** 3.92*** 2.66*** 3.94*** 27

28 (0.056) (0.089) (0.081) (0.525) ln(unemployment) 0.328*** 0.380*** 0.313*** 0.426*** (0.004) (0.007) (0.006) (0.044) age *** *** *** *** (7.38E-4) (0.001) (0.001) (0.008) age E-3*** -2.61E-3*** -7.35E-4*** -9.81E-4*** (1.52E-5) (2.16E-5) (2.12E-5) (1.54E-5) vehicle fixed effects X X X X year dummies X X X X month-of-year dummies X X X X driving period dummies X X X X R-squared N 30,621,721 14,773,863 15,555, ,310 Notes: Dependent variable is the log average VMT over the driving period scaled to one year. The log gasoline price is instrumented using the log refinery disruptions in all columns. Column 1 is estimated on the full dataset (identical to column 3 in Table 3), 2 on vehicles with a fuel economy below 20 MPG, 3 on vehicles with a fuel economy MPG, and 4 on vehicles with fuel economy greater than 30 MPG. R-squared values are the within R-squared. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at the vehicle level. *** denotes significant at the 1% level. The results from Table 6 show that drivers of vehicles in the lowest fuel economy bracket are the most responsive, with an elasticity of Interestingly, the coefficient on the gasoline price is close to zero and statistically insignificant in columns 3 and 4, suggesting that drivers of vehicles of higher fuel economy are barely responsive to changes in gasoline prices. These results provide strong evidence that the lowest fuel economy vehicles are the force behind the responsiveness to gasoline prices. There are several possible explanations for this result. One is that gasoline prices are simply more salient to consumers of lower fuel economy vehicles, due to their higher fuel bill. Another is the drivers of lower fuel economy vehicles are less wealthy and thus face a tighter budget constraint. Still another is that there may be within-household vehicle switching occurring, consistent with previous results in the literature, such as in Knittel and Sandler (2013). All these 28

29 effects could also be occurring concurrently, and we cannot disentangle them with our data. However, future work to understand these mechanisms could be valuable. 5.4 Heterogeneity in responsiveness by age of vehicles Understanding how the responsiveness to changing gasoline prices differs by the age and cohort of vehicles is useful for both forecasting driving by the fleet, as well as determining the changes in local air pollution from a policy. Specifically, many older vehicles are more polluting than new vehicles (although within the mandated guidelines from emissions inspections). If older vehicles are more responsive to changes in gasoline prices, this may imply that meeting local air pollution targets will be disproportionately easier when gasoline prices increase. 12 Table 7 provides similar results to previous tables, only using subsamples of the dataset based on the vehicle age. Again for ease of interpretation we choose three subsamples: vehicles with age less than 3 years, age between 3 and 7 years, and age greater than 7 years. The logic for these cut-offs is that vehicles less than three years old are very new and often leased, vehicles between 3 and 7 years make up the bulk of VMT of owned vehicles, while vehicles older than 7 years are driven less. Columns 2, 3, and 4 in Table 7 present the results from each of these subsets of the data respectively. Column 1 again shows the results estimated on the full dataset for reference. 12 Note that the average fuel economy of the fleet has not changed significantly over the time period; it has hovered around 21 mpg in all of those years. 29

Heterogeneity in the Response to Gasoline Prices: Evidence from Pennsylvania and Implications for the Rebound Effect

Heterogeneity in the Response to Gasoline Prices: Evidence from Pennsylvania and Implications for the Rebound Effect 1 Heterogeneity in the Response to Gasoline Prices: Evidence from Pennsylvania and Implications for the Rebound Effect Alan Jenn Inês Azevedo Kenneth Gillingham * Carnegie-Mellon University Yale University

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER. The Rebound Effect for Passenger Vehicles. J o s h u a L i n n P St. NW Washington, DC

DISCUSSION PAPER. The Rebound Effect for Passenger Vehicles. J o s h u a L i n n P St. NW Washington, DC DISCUSSION PAPER Jul y 2013; revised November 2013 RFF DP 13-19-REV The Rebound Effect for Passenger Vehicles J o s h u a L i n n 1616 P St. NW Washington, DC 20036 202-328-5000 www.rff.org The Rebound

More information

Rebound Effect: Overview and Recent Research. Joshua Linn NYU Transportation Workshop October 2011

Rebound Effect: Overview and Recent Research. Joshua Linn NYU Transportation Workshop October 2011 Rebound Effect: Overview and Recent Research Joshua Linn NYU Transportation Workshop October 2011 What Is the Rebound Effect? Passenger vehicle fuel economy regulation Corporate average fuel economy (CAFE)

More information

Prepared by: Kenneth Gillingham, PhD Yale University

Prepared by: Kenneth Gillingham, PhD Yale University The Rebound Effect of Fuel Economy Standards: Comment on the Safer Affordable Fuel-Efficient (SAFE) Vehicles Proposed Rule for Model Years 2021-2026 Passenger Cars and Light Trucks Prepared by: Kenneth

More information

What Do We Know about Gasoline Demand Elasticities?

What Do We Know about Gasoline Demand Elasticities? What Do We Know about Gasoline Demand Elasticities? Carol A. Dahl Colorado School of Mines Working Paper http://dahl.mines.edu/courses/courses/dedd/dahl_g06.pdf November 2006 Numerous studies have been

More information

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods Mark R. Jacobsen, 1,5 Christopher R. Knittel, 2,5 James M. Sallee, 3,5 Arthur A. van Benthem 4,5 December 8, 2014

More information

How Much Ethanol Can Be Consumed in E85?

How Much Ethanol Can Be Consumed in E85? Iowa State University Digital Repository @ Iowa State University CARD Briefing Papers CARD Reports and Working Papers 9-2015 How Much Ethanol Can Be Consumed in E85? Sebastien Pouliot Iowa State University,

More information

Preparing for the Midterm Review of the Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Rate Standards for Light-Duty Vehicles

Preparing for the Midterm Review of the Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Rate Standards for Light-Duty Vehicles Date Issue Brief # I S S U E B R I E F Preparing for the Midterm Review of the Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Rate Standards for Light-Duty Vehicles A Summary of Priority Research Questions

More information

Summer Fuels Outlook. Gasoline and diesel. April 2018

Summer Fuels Outlook. Gasoline and diesel. April 2018 April 2018 Summer Fuels Outlook This outlook focuses on prices and consumption of gasoline, diesel, and electricity (see Summer Fuels Outlook motor gasoline table and electricity table). The use of these

More information

A Tale of Two Tails: Commuting and the Fuel Price Response in Driving

A Tale of Two Tails: Commuting and the Fuel Price Response in Driving A Tale of Two Tails: Commuting and the Fuel Price Response in Driving Kenneth Gillingham, Yale University and NBER Anders Munk-Nielsen, University of Copenhagen November 26, 2017 Abstract Pricing greenhouse

More information

The Implied Cost of Carbon Dioxide Under the Cash for Clunkers Program

The Implied Cost of Carbon Dioxide Under the Cash for Clunkers Program CSEM WP 189 The Implied Cost of Carbon Dioxide Under the Cash for Clunkers Program Christopher R. Knittel August 2009 This paper is part of the Center for the Study of Energy Markets (CSEM) Working Paper

More information

Cost-Effective Policies to Reduce Vehicle Emissions

Cost-Effective Policies to Reduce Vehicle Emissions Cost-Effective Policies to Reduce Vehicle Emissions By DON FULLERTON AND LI GAN* To compare cost-effectiveness of different abatement methods, many studies estimate production or cost functions and plot

More information

Do U.S. Households Favor Higher Efficiency Vehicles When Fuel Prices Increase? Valerie J. Karplus

Do U.S. Households Favor Higher Efficiency Vehicles When Fuel Prices Increase? Valerie J. Karplus Do U.S. Households Favor Higher Efficiency Vehicles When Fuel Prices Increase? Valerie J. Karplus Submission for Dennis J. O'Brien USAEE/IAEE Best Student Paper Award July 8, 2010 Households owning multiple

More information

Evidence of a Shift in the Short-Run Price Elasticity of Gasoline Demand

Evidence of a Shift in the Short-Run Price Elasticity of Gasoline Demand Evidence of a Shift in the Short-Run Price Elasticity of Gasoline Demand Jonathan E. Hughes, Christopher R. Knittel, and Daniel Sperling ABSTRACT Understanding the sensitivity of gasoline demand to changes

More information

America s Carbon Cliff

America s Carbon Cliff 1 Shrink That Footprint is an independent research group devoted to helping people concerned about climate change understand, calculate and reduce their carbon footprints. In particular we focus on reducing

More information

Explaining and Understanding Declines in U.S. CO 2 Emissions

Explaining and Understanding Declines in U.S. CO 2 Emissions Explaining and Understanding Declines in U.S. CO 2 Emissions Zeke Hausfather Seven key factors, combined with the impacts of a prolonged economic slowdown, have led U.S. CO2 emissions to fall to 1996 levels,

More information

CAFE in the City - A Spatial Analysis of Fuel Economy Standards and Fuel Taxes

CAFE in the City - A Spatial Analysis of Fuel Economy Standards and Fuel Taxes CAFE in the City - A Spatial Analysis of Fuel Economy Standards and Fuel Taxes Waldemar Marz a,1, Frank Goetzke b a Ifo Institute, Department for Energy, Climate and Resources, Poschingerstr. 5, 81679

More information

FHWA Forecasts of Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT): May 2014

FHWA Forecasts of Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT): May 2014 FHWA Forecasts of Vehicle Miles Traveled (VMT): May 2014 Office of Highway Policy Information Federal Highway Administration May 22, 2014 Highlights Long-Term Economic Outlook Under the IHS Baseline economic

More information

Internet and the Efficiency of Decentralized Markets: Evidence from Automobiles 1

Internet and the Efficiency of Decentralized Markets: Evidence from Automobiles 1 Internet and the Efficiency of Decentralized Markets: Evidence from Automobiles 1 David Rapson 2 and Pasquale Schiraldi 3 April 14, 2013 Abstract We estimate the effect of Internet on volume of trade in

More information

THE CONSUMER BENEFITS OF THE PROPOSED FUEL ECONOMY STANDARDS: A PRELIMINARY ASSESSMENT. Mark Cooper, Director of Research JANUARY 2012

THE CONSUMER BENEFITS OF THE PROPOSED FUEL ECONOMY STANDARDS: A PRELIMINARY ASSESSMENT. Mark Cooper, Director of Research JANUARY 2012 THE CONSUMER BENEFITS OF THE PROPOSED FUEL ECONOMY STANDARDS: A PRELIMINARY ASSESSMENT Mark Cooper, Director of Research JANUARY 2012 CONSUMER BENEFITS OF HIGHER FUEL ECONOMY STANDARDS The Consumer Federation

More information

An Econometric Approach to Forecasting Vehicle Miles Traveled in Wisconsin

An Econometric Approach to Forecasting Vehicle Miles Traveled in Wisconsin 0 0 0 An Econometric Approach to Forecasting Vehicle Miles Traveled in Wisconsin Mike Sillence Traffic Forecasting Section Wisconsin Department of Transportation 0 Sheboygan Avenue, Room 0 Madison, WI

More information

Econ 366 Energy Economics. Fall 2012 Transportation Energy Demand

Econ 366 Energy Economics. Fall 2012 Transportation Energy Demand Econ 366 Energy Economics Fall 2012 Transportation Energy Demand Transportation Energy Demand Two major components: passenger (fuel consumption per passenger mile x passenger miles) and freight (fuel consumption

More information

AN ESTIMATION OF THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE IN MONTANA, AND PROJECTIONS OF FUTURE GASOLINE CONSUMPTION. Aaron David McNay

AN ESTIMATION OF THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE IN MONTANA, AND PROJECTIONS OF FUTURE GASOLINE CONSUMPTION. Aaron David McNay AN ESTIMATION OF THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE IN MONTANA, AND PROJECTIONS OF FUTURE GASOLINE CONSUMPTION by Aaron David McNay A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of

More information

Econ 1101 International Application Case Studies

Econ 1101 International Application Case Studies Econ 1101 International Application Case Studies InterApp 2: Fuel Consumption in Europe and the United States And Long-Run Elasticity of Demand By Thomas J. Holmes, Dept. of Economics, University of Minnesota

More information

Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector

Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector Demand for Niche Local Brands in the Fluid Milk Sector Yizao Liu Assistant Professor Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Connecticut yizao.liu@uconn.edu Adam N. Rabinowitz Assistant

More information

EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in)

EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in) Econ. 240B, Second Half Daniel McFadden, 2001 EXERCISE 5. THE MARKET FOR GASOLINE (Not to be handed in) Several oil refinery accidents in California in the Spring of 1999 restricted production of gasoline

More information

CAPITAL INTENSITY AND U.S. COUNTRY POPULATION GROWTH DURING THE LATE NINETEENTH CENTURY WORKING PAPER SERIES

CAPITAL INTENSITY AND U.S. COUNTRY POPULATION GROWTH DURING THE LATE NINETEENTH CENTURY WORKING PAPER SERIES WORKING PAPER NO. 2012 02 CAPITAL INTENSITY AND U.S. COUNTRY POPULATION GROWTH DURING THE LATE NINETEENTH CENTURY By Burton A. Abrams, Jing Li and James G. Mulligan WORKING PAPER SERIES The views expressed

More information

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered Beyond balanced growth 11 PartA Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered Uwe Sunde and Thomas Vischer Abstract: Human capital plays a central role in theoretical

More information

Estimating Impacts of a Vehicle Mile Tax on Oregon Households By Kyle Nakahara, Oregon State University September 2007

Estimating Impacts of a Vehicle Mile Tax on Oregon Households By Kyle Nakahara, Oregon State University September 2007 Estimating Impacts of a Vehicle Mile Tax on Oregon Households By Kyle Nakahara, Oregon State University September 2007 ABSTRACT Oregon s gasoline tax no longer serves as an economically efficient revenue

More information

impact Understanding the regulatory environment of climate change and the A P P E N D I X 1 of community design on greenhouse gas emissions.

impact Understanding the regulatory environment of climate change and the A P P E N D I X 1 of community design on greenhouse gas emissions. A P P E N D I X 1 Understanding the regulatory environment of climate change and the impact of community design on greenhouse gas emissions. Transportation, Planning, Land Use and Air Quality Conference

More information

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay I. Theoretical Model In this paper, I define skill-biased technological change as the technological shock that began in the 1970s with

More information

crossmark Energy Policy Feasibility of meeting increased biofuel mandates with E85 Sébastien Pouliot, Bruce A. Babcock ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

crossmark Energy Policy Feasibility of meeting increased biofuel mandates with E85 Sébastien Pouliot, Bruce A. Babcock ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT Energy Policy 101 (2017) 194 200 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Energy Policy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol Feasibility of meeting increased biofuel mandates with E85 Sébastien

More information

Entry and Pricing on Broadway

Entry and Pricing on Broadway Entry and Pricing on Broadway Taylor Jaworski Maggie E.C. Jones Mario Samano June 29, 2017 Abstract This paper investigates the pricing decisions of Broadway shows. We find evidence that incumbent Broadway

More information

HIGH FREQUENCY EVIDENCE ON THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE

HIGH FREQUENCY EVIDENCE ON THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE HIGH FREQUENCY EVIDENCE ON THE DEMAND FOR GASOLINE LAURENCE LEVIN MATTHEW S. LEWIS FRANK A. WOLAK Forthcoming in the American Economic Journal: Economic Policy Draft Date: October 20, 2016 Abstract Daily

More information

Obstacles to Registering: Necessity vs. Opportunity Entrepreneurs

Obstacles to Registering: Necessity vs. Opportunity Entrepreneurs Obstacles to Registering: Necessity vs. Opportunity Entrepreneurs Mohammad Amin* December, 2009 Using a new dataset on informal or unregistered firms in Ivory Coast, Madagascar and Mauritius, this paper

More information

Skimming from the bottom: Empirical evidence of adverse selection when poaching customers Online Appendix

Skimming from the bottom: Empirical evidence of adverse selection when poaching customers Online Appendix Skimming from the bottom: Empirical evidence of adverse selection when poaching customers Online Appendix Przemys law Jeziorski Elena Krasnokutskaya Olivia Ceccarini January 22, 2018 Corresponding author.

More information

PAYING THE FREIGHT: THE CONSUMER BENEFITS OF INCREASING THE FUEL ECONOMY OF MEDIUM AND HEAVY DUTY TRUCKS VERSION 2.0

PAYING THE FREIGHT: THE CONSUMER BENEFITS OF INCREASING THE FUEL ECONOMY OF MEDIUM AND HEAVY DUTY TRUCKS VERSION 2.0 2 PAYING THE FREIGHT: THE CONSUMER BENEFITS OF INCREASING THE FUEL ECONOMY OF MEDIUM AND HEAVY DUTY TRUCKS VERSION 2.0 Dr. Mark Cooper Director of Research, CFA With contributions from Jack Gillis Director

More information

Key Findings. Background and Introduction

Key Findings. Background and Introduction Analysis of Whether the Prices of Renewable Fuel Standard RINs Have Affected Retail Gasoline Prices Prepared for the Renewable Fuels Association October 2017 Key Findings Changes in the prices of renewable

More information

ENERGY USE AND INTENSITY IN THE INDUSTRIAL SECTOR D. B. Belzer, Pacific Northwest Laboratory(a)

ENERGY USE AND INTENSITY IN THE INDUSTRIAL SECTOR D. B. Belzer, Pacific Northwest Laboratory(a) ENERGY USE AND INTENSITY IN THE INDUSTRIAL SECTOR 9 1972-1991 D. B. Belzer, Pacific Northwest Laboratory(a) Energy use in the United States is substantially lower now than it would have been had energy

More information

Gasoline Taxes and Consumer Behavior

Gasoline Taxes and Consumer Behavior Gasoline Taxes and Consumer Behavior Shanjun Li 1 Joshua Linn 2 Erich Muehlegger 3 1 Resources for the Future 2 Resources for the Future 3 Harvard Kennedy School and NBER Chicago-RFF Conference June 21,

More information

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Energy Policy

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Energy Policy Energy Policy ] (]]]]) ]]] ]]] Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Energy Policy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol Rebound 2007: Analysis of U.S. light-duty vehicle travel statistics

More information

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS Dimitrios A. Giannias Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie-Mellon University Dissertation Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the

More information

Energy Economics 45 (2014) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Energy Economics. journal homepage:

Energy Economics 45 (2014) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Energy Economics. journal homepage: Energy Economics 45 (2014) 244 253 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Energy Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/eneco Modeling gasoline demand in the United States: A flexible semiparametric

More information

Electrification and Decarbonization

Electrification and Decarbonization Electrification and Decarbonization Geoffrey J. Blanford, Ph.D. Technical Executive Energy and Environmental Analysis, EPRI Energy and Climate Seminar, Washington, DC May 10, 2017 Reducing carbon emissions

More information

Energy-Economic-Environment Model for Policy Analysis in California: Elastic Demand and Sensitivity Analysis in MARKAL/TIMES

Energy-Economic-Environment Model for Policy Analysis in California: Elastic Demand and Sensitivity Analysis in MARKAL/TIMES Energy-Economic-Environment Model for Policy Analysis in California: Elastic Demand and Sensitivity Analysis in MARKAL/TIMES Kalai Ramea, Sonia Yeh, Chris Yang Institute of Transportation Studies, University

More information

U.S. Carbon Dioxide Emissions in 2009: A Retrospective Review

U.S. Carbon Dioxide Emissions in 2009: A Retrospective Review U.S. Carbon Dioxide Emissions in 2009: A Retrospective Review The U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA) recently expanded its reporting of energyrelated carbon dioxide emissions starting in the

More information

Analysis of Transportation Greenhouse Gas Reduction Strategies in Massachusetts Using the EERPAT Tool

Analysis of Transportation Greenhouse Gas Reduction Strategies in Massachusetts Using the EERPAT Tool Analysis of Transportation Greenhouse Gas Reduction Strategies in Massachusetts Using the EERPAT Tool Christopher D. Porter, Cambridge Systematics, Inc., 100 CambridgePark Drive, Suite 400, Cambridge,

More information

The economic benefits of wind energy in the Southwest Power Pool

The economic benefits of wind energy in the Southwest Power Pool The economic benefits of wind energy in the Southwest Power Pool November 2014 Introduction Wind energy provides the Southwest Power Pool region (Kansas, Oklahoma, Nebraska, and parts of New Mexico, Texas,

More information

The Price and Income Elasticity Demand for Gasoline in the United States. Abstract

The Price and Income Elasticity Demand for Gasoline in the United States. Abstract The Price and Income Elasticity Demand for Gasoline in the United States By: Mark Groza Undergraduate: University of Akron (BSLE) May 5, 2006 Abstract Why do Americans consume so much gasoline? This is

More information

University of Hawai i Economic Research Organization 2424 Maile Way, Room 540 Honolulu, Hawai i

University of Hawai i Economic Research Organization 2424 Maile Way, Room 540 Honolulu, Hawai i Energy and Greenhouse Gas Solutions Targeting Hawai i Greenhouse Gas Emissions Reductions: Emission Forecasts for 2020 and Their Implications for Act 234 2009 University of Hawai i Economic Research Organization

More information

By Adonis Yatchew and Joungyeo Angela No 1

By Adonis Yatchew and Joungyeo Angela No 1 Econometrica, Vol. 69, No. 6 (November, 2001), 1697 1709 HOUSEHOLD GASOLINE DEMAND IN CANADA By Adonis Yatchew and Joungyeo Angela No 1 1 introduction Several recent studies analyze demand for gasoline

More information

Congress, Congressional Research Service, , R41836, The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: Lessons Learned and Issues for Congress.

Congress, Congressional Research Service, , R41836, The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: Lessons Learned and Issues for Congress. Historical Data Considerations of the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative and Implications for Going Forward Environmental Energy Alliance of New York June 1, 2016 The Environmental Energy Alliance of New

More information

MARNA KEARNEY Energy Research Centre University of cape Town

MARNA KEARNEY Energy Research Centre University of cape Town Modelling the impact of CO 2 taxes in combination with the Long Term Mitigations Scenarios on Emissions in South Africa using a dynamic computable general equilibrium model MARNA KEARNEY 2008 Energy Research

More information

The Impact of Global Warming on U.S. Agriculture: An Econometric Analysis of Optimal Growing Conditions. Additional Material Available on Request

The Impact of Global Warming on U.S. Agriculture: An Econometric Analysis of Optimal Growing Conditions. Additional Material Available on Request The Impact of Global Warming on U.S. Agriculture: An Econometric Analysis of Optimal Growing Conditions Additional Material Available on Request Contents A Robustness Checks B Untransformed Climate Variables

More information

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services

The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services The cyclicality of mark-ups and profit margins: some evidence for manufacturing and services By Ian Small of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. This article (1) reviews how price-cost mark-ups

More information

Context. Case Study: Albany, New York. Overview

Context. Case Study: Albany, New York. Overview Case Study: Albany, New York Overview The Capital District, a four-county region surrounding Albany, New York, has experienced dramatic growth in vehicle-miles of travel (VMT) in recent years, which has

More information

Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage

Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage Anja Lambrecht London Business School alambrecht@london.edu Catherine Tucker Katja Seim University

More information

The U.S. Over-Supply of Oil is Ending

The U.S. Over-Supply of Oil is Ending The U.S. Over-Supply of Oil is Ending Pay-It-Forward Network Art Berman November 17, 217 Slide 1 The U.S. Over-Supply of Oil is Ending The U.S. Over-Supply of Oil is Ending 11 WTI Price Stocks 239 213

More information

Economic Outcomes of a U.S. Carbon Tax. Executive Summary

Economic Outcomes of a U.S. Carbon Tax. Executive Summary Economic Outcomes of a U.S. Carbon Tax Executive Summary [ Overview [ During the ongoing debate on how to address our nation s fiscal challenges, some have suggested that imposing a carbon tax would improve

More information

THE ECONOMIC AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF PHILLYCARSHARE IN THE PHILADELPHIA REGION

THE ECONOMIC AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF PHILLYCARSHARE IN THE PHILADELPHIA REGION THE ECONOMIC AND ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACT OF PHILLYCARSHARE IN THE PHILADELPHIA REGION Final Report Submitted To: PhillyCarShare 125 South 9th Street Suite 1000 Philadelphia PA 19107 Final Report Submitted

More information

Chapter 2. Data and base case considerations 2.1 The data underlying IGEM and its parameter estimates

Chapter 2. Data and base case considerations 2.1 The data underlying IGEM and its parameter estimates Chapter 2. Data and base case considerations 2.1 The data underlying IGEM and its parameter estimates The inter-industry accounts of the system of U.S. national accounts provide the core structure for

More information

Examining the Short-Run Price Elasticity of Gasoline Demand in the United States

Examining the Short-Run Price Elasticity of Gasoline Demand in the United States Clemson University TigerPrints All Theses Theses 12-2012 Examining the Short-Run Price Elasticity of Gasoline Demand in the United States Michael Brannan Clemson University, michael.brannan4@gmail.com

More information

The Cost of Reducing Gasoline Consumption. by Sarah E. West and Roberton C. Williams III*

The Cost of Reducing Gasoline Consumption. by Sarah E. West and Roberton C. Williams III* The Cost of Reducing Gasoline Consumption by Sarah E. West and Roberton C. Williams III* I. Introduction High nominal gas prices, new awareness of threats to national security, and growing concern about

More information

Do Automotive Fuel Economy Standards Increase Rates of Technology Change?

Do Automotive Fuel Economy Standards Increase Rates of Technology Change? Do Automotive Fuel Economy Standards Increase Rates of Technology Change? Don MacKenzie PhD Candidate, Engineering Systems Division, MIT Presented at USAEE/IAEE North American Conference November 5, 2012

More information

Digitalization, Skilled labor and the Productivity of Firms 1

Digitalization, Skilled labor and the Productivity of Firms 1 Digitalization, Skilled labor and the Productivity of Firms 1 Jóannes Jacobsen, Jan Rose Skaksen and Anders Sørensen, CEBR, Copenhagen Business School 1. Introduction In the literature on information technology

More information

Vector Space Modeling for Aggregate and Industry Sectors in Kuwait

Vector Space Modeling for Aggregate and Industry Sectors in Kuwait Vector Space Modeling for Aggregate and Industry Sectors in Kuwait Kevin Lawler 1 1 Central Statistical Bureau: State of Kuwait/ U.N.D.P Abstract. Trend growth in total factor productivity (TFP) is unobserved;

More information

Cleaning the Bathwater with the Baby: The Health Co- Benefits of Carbon Pricing in Transportation

Cleaning the Bathwater with the Baby: The Health Co- Benefits of Carbon Pricing in Transportation EI @ Haas WP 219 Cleaning the Bathwater with the Baby: The Health Co- Benefits of Carbon Pricing in Transportation Christopher R. Knittel and Ryan Sandler August 2011 Energy Institute at Haas working papers

More information

SIEPR policy brief. Living on a Budget. Matthew Harding. About The Author. Stanford University December 2009

SIEPR policy brief. Living on a Budget. Matthew Harding. About The Author. Stanford University December 2009 SIEPR policy brief Stanford University December 2009 Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research on the web: http://siepr.stanford.edu Living on a Budget Matthew Harding The grocery market in the United

More information

The MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change Massachusetts Institute of Technology

The MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change Massachusetts Institute of Technology Should a vehicle fuel economy standard be combined with an economy-wide greenhouse gas emissions constraint? Implications for energy and climate policy in the United States Valerie J. Karplus 1, Sergey

More information

The consumer and societal benefits of wind energy in Texas

The consumer and societal benefits of wind energy in Texas The consumer and societal benefits of wind energy in Texas November 2014 Introduction Texas wind energy provides the state with $3.3 billion in societal benefits per year. These benefits include reducing

More information

The Impact of Ethanol Production on U.S. and Regional Gasoline Markets: An Update to 2012

The Impact of Ethanol Production on U.S. and Regional Gasoline Markets: An Update to 2012 CARD Working Papers CARD Reports and Working Papers 5-2012 The Impact of Ethanol Production on U.S. and Regional Gasoline Markets: An Update to 2012 Xiaodong Du University of Wisconsin Madison, xdu@iastate.edu

More information

Online Appendix for Are Online and Offline Prices Similar? Evidence from Multi-Channel Retailers

Online Appendix for Are Online and Offline Prices Similar? Evidence from Multi-Channel Retailers Online Appendix for Are Online and Offline Prices Similar? Evidence from Multi-Channel Retailers Alberto Cavallo MIT & NBER This version: August 29, 2016 A Appendix A.1 Price-level Comparison with Amazon.com

More information

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade?

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade? Zahoor Haq Post-Doctoral Fellow, Department of Food, Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Guelph, Canada and Lecturer, WFP

More information

Impacts of Announced Nuclear Retirements in Ohio and Pennsylvania

Impacts of Announced Nuclear Retirements in Ohio and Pennsylvania Impacts of Announced Nuclear Retirements in Ohio and Pennsylvania Dean Murphy and Mark Berkman April 2018 The owners of four nuclear plants in Ohio and Pennsylvania have announced that these plants will

More information

Mergers and Sequential Innovation: Evidence from Patent Citations

Mergers and Sequential Innovation: Evidence from Patent Citations Mergers and Sequential Innovation: Evidence from Patent Citations Jessica Calfee Stahl Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System January 2010 Abstract An extensive literature has investigated the

More information

Dispersion in Wage Premiums and Firm Performance

Dispersion in Wage Premiums and Firm Performance Working Papers, Centre for Globalisation Research No. 8 (April 2008) ISSN 1755-5892 Dispersion in Wage Premiums and Firm Performance by Pedro Martins Working papers are in draft form. This working paper

More information

Retail Pricing under Contract Self-Selection: An Empirical Exploration

Retail Pricing under Contract Self-Selection: An Empirical Exploration Technology and Investment, 2013, 4, 31-35 Published Online February 2013 (http://www.scirp.org/journal/ti) Retail Pricing under Contract Self-Selection: An Empirical Exploration Yuanfang Lin, Lianhua Li

More information

Energy Consumption Trends in the Danish Transport Sector

Energy Consumption Trends in the Danish Transport Sector Energy Consumption Trends in the Danish Transport Sector By Economist Helene Sneftrup Jensen, Danish Energy Agency, December 2000 1. Introduction The Danish Energy Agency publishes a yearly report about

More information

2015 Statewide Greenhouse Gas Emissions Inventory

2015 Statewide Greenhouse Gas Emissions Inventory 2015 Statewide Greenhouse Gas Emissions Inventory December 2017 2015 Update to New Jersey s Statewide Greenhouse Gas (GHG) Emissions Inventory Introduction The previous GHG Emissions Inventory update,

More information

US climate change impacts from the PAGE2002 integrated assessment model used in the Stern report

US climate change impacts from the PAGE2002 integrated assessment model used in the Stern report Page 1 of 54 16 November 27 US climate change impacts from the PAGE22 integrated assessment model used in the Stern report Chris Hope & Stephan Alberth Judge Business School, University of Cambridge, UK

More information

SIEPR policy brief. Low-Carbon Fuel Standards: Do They Really Work? By Frank A. Wolak. About The Author. Stanford University May 2008

SIEPR policy brief. Low-Carbon Fuel Standards: Do They Really Work? By Frank A. Wolak. About The Author. Stanford University May 2008 SIEPR policy brief Stanford University May 2008 Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research on the web: http://siepr.stanford.edu Low-Carbon Fuel Standards: Do They Really Work? By Frank A. Wolak Transportation

More information

Induced Demand and Rebound Effects in Road Transport

Induced Demand and Rebound Effects in Road Transport Induced Demand and Rebound Effects in Road Transport Kent M. Hymel, Kenneth A. Small, and Kurt Van Dender Department of Economics, UC Irvine February 2009 2 Measure three effects of policies or technological

More information

Rebound effects in GB road transport. Steve Sorrell and Lee Stapleton November 2015

Rebound effects in GB road transport. Steve Sorrell and Lee Stapleton November 2015 Rebound effects in GB road transport Steve Sorrell and Lee Stapleton November 2015 Topics Project outline Methodological challenges Estimating direct rebound effects in GB personal automotive transport

More information

The*Rebound*Effect*and*Energy*Efficiency*Policy*

The*Rebound*Effect*and*Energy*Efficiency*Policy* ! E2e*Working*Paper*013*!!!!! The*Rebound*Effect*and*Energy*Efficiency*Policy* Kenneth!Gillingham,!David!Rapson,!and!Gernot!Wagner! September!2015!! Published*in* Review&of&Environmental&Economics&and&Policy,*2016,*

More information

Summary of Impacts on Transit Ridership, The Transit Industry, Related Industries, and Energy Consumption

Summary of Impacts on Transit Ridership, The Transit Industry, Related Industries, and Energy Consumption Chapter IX Summary of Impacts on Transit Ridership, The Transit Industry, Related Industries, and Energy Consumption INTRODUCTION Chapter VIII reviewed the impact of various transit incentive and auto

More information

MIDDLE-INCOME JOB DECLINE IN PENNSYLVANIA

MIDDLE-INCOME JOB DECLINE IN PENNSYLVANIA MIDDLE-INCOME JOB DECLINE IN PENNSYLVANIA Update 2001-13: Business-Cycle, Great Recession and Recovery Prepared at the Center for Economic and Community Development by: Theodore R. Alter, Regional Economist

More information

The United States alone has less than 5% of the

The United States alone has less than 5% of the The Effect of Prices on Oil Demand in the Transportation and Residential Sectors Amy Cline I. Introduction The United States alone has less than 5% of the world s population, but uses 25% of the world

More information

Winter Fuels Outlook

Winter Fuels Outlook Robert Pirog Specialist in Energy Economics December 5, 2017 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R45042 Summary The Energy Information Administration (EIA), in its Short-Term Energy and Winter

More information

HOT AIR OVER THE ARCTIC? AN ASSESSMENT OF THE WEFA STUDY OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF OIL DRILLING IN THE ARCTIC NATIONAL WILDLIFE REFUGE

HOT AIR OVER THE ARCTIC? AN ASSESSMENT OF THE WEFA STUDY OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF OIL DRILLING IN THE ARCTIC NATIONAL WILDLIFE REFUGE cepr CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH briefing paper HOT AIR OVER THE ARCTIC? AN ASSESSMENT OF THE WEFA STUDY OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF OIL DRILLING IN THE ARCTIC NATIONAL WILDLIFE REFUGE by Dean

More information

Job Quality During the Expansion 1. Loretta J. Mester and Guhan Venkatu Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland March 2015

Job Quality During the Expansion 1. Loretta J. Mester and Guhan Venkatu Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland March 2015 Job Quality During the Expansion 1 Loretta J. Mester and Guhan Venkatu Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland March 2015 1. Introduction After the Great Recession began in December 2007, U.S. nonfarm payroll

More information

The Basics of Supply and Demand

The Basics of Supply and Demand C H A P T E R 2 The Basics of Supply and Demand Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano CHAPTER 2 OUTLINE 2.1 Supply and Demand 2.2 The Market Mechanism 2.3 Changes in Market Equilibrium 2.4 Elasticities

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES POLICY-INSTRUMENT CHOICE AND BENEFIT ESTIMATES FOR CLIMATE-CHANGE POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES POLICY-INSTRUMENT CHOICE AND BENEFIT ESTIMATES FOR CLIMATE-CHANGE POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES POLICY-INSTRUMENT CHOICE AND BENEFIT ESTIMATES FOR CLIMATE-CHANGE POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES Matthew J. Kotchen Kevin J. Boyle Anthony A. Leiserowitz Working Paper 17539 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17539

More information

ESTIMATING THE EFFECT OF A GASOLINE TAX ON CARBON EMISSIONS

ESTIMATING THE EFFECT OF A GASOLINE TAX ON CARBON EMISSIONS JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMETRICS J. Appl. Econ. 26: 1187 1214 (2011) Published online 4 February 2010 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).1156 ESTIMATING THE EFFECT OF A GASOLINE TAX ON CARBON

More information

Global Warming: A Threat Not to Be Ignored

Global Warming: A Threat Not to Be Ignored State Clean Cars Programs: An Effective Way to Slash Global Warming Pollution 10-State Clean Car Standards to Cut 64 Million Metric Tons of Global Warming Emissions per Year by 2020 Shrinking glaciers,

More information

Estimating Impacts of a Vehicle Mile Tax on Oregon Households. by Kyle S. Nakahara A THESIS. submitted to. Oregon State University

Estimating Impacts of a Vehicle Mile Tax on Oregon Households. by Kyle S. Nakahara A THESIS. submitted to. Oregon State University Estimating Impacts of a Vehicle Mile Tax on Oregon Households by Kyle S. Nakahara A THESIS submitted to Oregon State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science

More information

GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK

GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK Chapter Six GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK This chapter attempts to derive rough estimates of the adverse effects on Chinese GDP growth attendant upon an energy price shock, defined as a substantial

More information

The Basics of Supply and Demand

The Basics of Supply and Demand C H A P T E R 2 The Basics of Supply and Demand Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano CHAPTER 2 OUTLINE 2.1 Supply and Demand 2.2 The Market Mechanism 2.3 Changes in Market Equilibrium 2.4 Elasticities

More information

A Semiparametric Analysis of Gasoline Demand in the US: Reexamining The Impact of Price

A Semiparametric Analysis of Gasoline Demand in the US: Reexamining The Impact of Price A Semiparametric Analysis of Gasoline Demand in the US: Reexamining The Impact of Price Sebastiano Manzan and Dawit Zerom Department of Economics and Finance, Baruch College (CUNY), USA Mihaylo College

More information

Conventional versus Innovative Technologies in the Transportation Sector: External Costs and Benefits

Conventional versus Innovative Technologies in the Transportation Sector: External Costs and Benefits Conventional versus Innovative Technologies in the Transportation Sector: External Costs and Benefits by Kenneth B Medlock III El Paso Corporation Department of Economics, Rice University Ron Soligo Department

More information

An Introduction to Cap-and-Trade Programs

An Introduction to Cap-and-Trade Programs 1 Investment & Finance An Introduction to Cap-and-Trade Programs The Evaluation Criteria Used in This Study Produced by the Congressional Budget Office A carbon cap and trade system has long been rumored

More information